WWW.DISSERTATION.XLIBX.INFO
FREE ELECTRONIC LIBRARY - Dissertations, online materials
 
<< HOME
CONTACTS



Pages:   || 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 |   ...   | 8 |

«The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns ANDREW ANG, ROBERT J. HODRICK, YUHANG XING, and XIAOYAN ZHANG∗ ABSTRACT We examine the pricing ...»

-- [ Page 1 ] --

THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE • VOL. LXI, NO. 1 • FEBRUARY 2006

The Cross-Section of Volatility

and Expected Returns

ANDREW ANG, ROBERT J. HODRICK, YUHANG XING, and XIAOYAN ZHANG∗

ABSTRACT

We examine the pricing of aggregate volatility risk in the cross-section of stock returns.

Consistent with theory, we find that stocks with high sensitivities to innovations in

aggregate volatility have low average returns. Stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility relative to the Fama and French (1993, Journal of Financial Economics 25, 2349) model have abysmally low average returns. This phenomenon cannot be explained by exposure to aggregate volatility risk. Size, book-to-market, momentum, and liquidity effects cannot account for either the low average returns earned by stocks with high exposure to systematic volatility risk or for the low average returns of stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility.

IT IS WELL KNOWN THAT THE VOLATILITY OF STOCK RETURNS varies over time. While con- siderable research has examined the time-series relation between the volatility of the market and the expected return on the market (see, among others, Camp- bell and Hentschel (1992) and Glosten, Jagannathan, and Runkle (1993)), the question of how aggregate volatility affects the cross-section of expected stock returns has received less attention. Time-varying market volatility induces changes in the investment opportunity set by changing the expectation of fu- ture market returns, or by changing the risk-return trade-off. If the volatility of the market return is a systematic risk factor, the arbitrage pricing theory or a factor model predicts that aggregate volatility should also be priced in the cross-section of stocks. Hence, stocks with different sensitivities to innovations in aggregate volatility should have different expected returns.

The first goal of this paper is to provide a systematic investigation of how the stochastic volatility of the market is priced in the cross-section of expected stock returns. We want to both determine whether the volatility of the market ∗ Ang is with Columbia University and NBER. Hodrick is with Columbia University and NBER.

Yuhang Xing is at Rice University. Xiaoyan Zhang is at Cornell University. We thank Joe Chen, Mike Chernov, Miguel Ferreira, Jeff Fleming, Chris Lamoureux, Jun Liu, Laurie Hodrick, Paul Hribar, Jun Pan, Matt Rhodes-Kropf, Steve Ross, David Weinbaum, and Lu Zhang for helpful discussions.

We also received valuable comments from seminar participants at an NBER Asset Pricing meeting, Campbell and Company, Columbia University, Cornell University, Hong Kong University, Rice University, UCLA, and the University of Rochester. We thank Tim Bollerslev, Joe Chen, Miguel Ferreira, Kenneth French, Anna Scherbina, and Tyler Shumway for kindly providing data. We especially thank an anonymous referee and Rob Stambaugh, the editor, for helpful suggestions that greatly improved the paper. Andrew Ang and Bob Hodrick both acknowledge support from the National Science Foundation.

–  –  –

is a priced risk factor and estimate the price of aggregate volatility risk. Many option studies have estimated a negative price of risk for market volatility using options on an aggregate market index or options on individual stocks.1 Using the cross-section of stock returns, rather than options on the market, allows us to create portfolios of stocks that have different sensitivities to innovations in market volatility. If the price of aggregate volatility risk is negative, stocks with large, positive sensitivities to volatility risk should have low average returns.

Using the cross-section of stock returns also allows us to easily control for a battery of cross-sectional effects, such as the size and value factors of Fama and French (1993), the momentum effect of Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), and ´ the effect of liquidity risk documented by Pastor and Stambaugh (2003). Option pricing studies do not control for these cross-sectional risk factors.

We find that innovations in aggregate volatility carry a statistically significant negative price of risk of approximately −1% per annum. Economic theory provides several reasons why the price of risk of innovations in market volatility should be negative. For example, Campbell (1993, 1996) and Chen (2002) show that investors want to hedge against changes in market volatility, because increasing volatility represents a deterioration in investment opportunities. Risk-averse agents demand stocks that hedge against this risk. Periods of high volatility also tend to coincide with downward market movements (see French, Schwert, and Stambaugh (1987) and Campbell and Hentschel (1992)).

As Bakshi and Kapadia (2003) comment, assets with high sensitivities to market volatility risk provide hedges against market downside risk. The higher demand for assets with high systematic volatility loadings increases their price and lowers their average return. Finally, stocks that do badly when volatility increases tend to have negatively skewed returns over intermediate horizons, while stocks that do well when volatility rises tend to have positively skewed returns. If investors have preferences over coskewness (see Harvey and Siddique (2000)), stocks that have high sensitivities to innovations in market volatility are attractive and have low returns.2 The second goal of the paper is to examine the cross-sectional relationship between idiosyncratic volatility and expected returns, where idiosyncratic volatility is defined relative to the standard Fama and French (1993) model.3 If the Fama–French model is correct, forming portfolios by sorting on idiosyncratic volatility will obviously provide no difference in average returns. Nevertheless, if the Fama–French model is false, sorting in this way potentially provides a set 1 See, among others, Jackwerth and Rubinstein (1996), Bakshi, Cao and Chen (2000), Chernov and Ghysels (2000), Burashi and Jackwerth (2001), Coval and Shumway (2001), Benzoni (2002), Pan (2002), Bakshi and Kapadia (2003), Eraker, Johannes and Polson (2003), Jones (2003), and Carr and Wu (2003).





2 Bates (2001) and Vayanos (2004) provide recent structural models whose reduced form factor structures have a negative risk premium for volatility risk.

3 Recent studies examining total or idiosyncratic volatility focus on the average level of firmlevel volatility. For example, Campbell et al. (2001) and Xu and Malkiel (2003) document that idiosyncratic volatility has increased over time. Brown and Ferreira (2003) and Goyal and SantaClara (2003) argue that idiosyncratic volatility has positive predictive power for excess market returns, but this is disputed by Bali et al. (2004).

Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns 261 of assets that may have different exposures to aggregate volatility and hence different average returns. Our logic is the following. If aggregate volatility is a risk factor that is orthogonal to existing risk factors, the sensitivity of stocks to aggregate volatility times the movement in aggregate volatility will show up in the residuals of the Fama–French model. Firms with greater sensitivities to aggregate volatility should therefore have larger idiosyncratic volatilities relative to the Fama–French model, everything else being equal. Differences in the volatilities of firms’ true idiosyncratic errors, which are not priced, will make this relation noisy. We should be able to average out this noise by constructing portfolios of stocks to reveal that larger idiosyncratic volatilities relative to the Fama–French model correspond to greater sensitivities to movements in aggregate volatility and thus different average returns, if aggregate volatility risk is priced.

While high exposure to aggregate volatility risk tends to produce low expected returns, some economic theories suggest that idiosyncratic volatility should be positively related to expected returns. If investors demand compensation for not being able to diversify risk (see Malkiel and Xu (2002) and Jones and Rhodes-Kropf (2003)), then agents will demand a premium for holding stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility. Merton (1987) suggests that in an information-segmented market, firms with larger firm-specific variances require higher average returns to compensate investors for holding imperfectly diversified portfolios. Some behavioral models, like Barberis and Huang (2001), also predict that higher idiosyncratic volatility stocks should earn higher expected returns. Our results are directly opposite to these theories. We find that stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility have low average returns. There is a strongly significant difference of −1.06% per month between the average returns of the quintile portfolio with the highest idiosyncratic volatility stocks and the quintile portfolio with the lowest idiosyncratic volatility stocks.

In contrast to our results, earlier researchers either find a significantly positive relation between idiosyncratic volatility and average returns, or they fail to find any statistically significant relation between idiosyncratic volatility and average returns. For example, Lintner (1965) shows that idiosyncratic volatility carries a positive coefficient in cross-sectional regressions. Lehmann (1990) also finds a statistically significant, positive coefficient on idiosyncratic volatility over his full sample period. Similarly, Tinic and West (1986) and Malkiel and Xu (2002) unambiguously find that portfolios with higher idiosyncratic volatility have higher average returns, but they do not report any significance levels for their idiosyncratic volatility premiums. On the other hand, Longstaff (1989) finds that a cross-sectional regression coefficient on total variance for size-sorted portfolios carries an insignificant negative sign.

The difference between our results and the results of past studies is that the past literature either does not examine idiosyncratic volatility at the firm level, or does not directly sort stocks into portfolios ranked on this measure of interest. For example, Tinic and West (1986) work only with 20 portfolios sorted on market beta, while Malkiel and Xu (2002) work only with 100 portfolios sorted on market beta and size. Malkiel and Xu (2002) only use the idiosyncratic 262 The Journal of Finance volatility of one of the 100 beta/size portfolios to which a stock belongs to proxy for that stock’s idiosyncratic risk and, thus, do not examine firm-level idiosyncratic volatility. Hence, by not directly computing differences in average returns between stocks with low and high idiosyncratic volatilities, previous studies miss the strong negative relation between idiosyncratic volatility and average returns that we find.

The low average returns to stocks with high idiosyncratic volatilities could arise because stocks with high idiosyncratic volatilities may have high exposure to aggregate volatility risk, which lowers their average returns. We investigate this conjecture and find that this is not a complete explanation. Our idiosyncratic volatility results are also robust to controlling for value, size, liquidity, volume, dispersion of analysts’ forecasts, and momentum effects. We find the effect robust to different formation periods for computing idiosyncratic volatility and for different holding periods. The effect also persists in bull and bear markets, recessions and expansions, and volatile and stable periods. Hence, our results on idiosyncratic volatility represent a substantive puzzle.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section I, we examine how aggregate volatility is priced in the cross-section of stock returns. Section II documents that firms with high idiosyncratic volatility have very low average returns. Finally, Section III concludes.

I. Pricing Systematic Volatility in the Cross-Section A. Theoretical Motivation When investment opportunities vary over time, the multifactor models of Merton (1973) and Ross (1976) show that risk premia are associated with the conditional covariances between asset returns and innovations in state variables that describe the time-variation of the investment opportunities. Campbell’s (1993, 1996) version of the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (I-CAPM) shows that investors care about risks both from the market return and from changes in forecasts of future market returns. When the representative agent is more risk averse than log utility, assets that covary positively with good news about future expected returns on the market have higher average returns. These assets command a risk premium because they reduce a consumer’s ability to hedge against a deterioration in investment opportunities. The intuition from Campbell’s model is that risk-averse investors want to hedge against changes in aggregate volatility because volatility positively affects future expected market returns, as in Merton (1973).

However, in Campbell’s setup, there is no direct role for f luctuations in market volatility to affect the expected returns of assets because Campbell’s model is premised on homoskedasticity. Chen (2002) extends Campbell’s model to a heteroskedastic environment which allows for both time-varying covariances and stochastic market volatility. Chen shows that risk-averse investors also want to directly hedge against changes in future market volatility. In Chen’s model, an asset’s expected return depends on risk from the market return, Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns 263

–  –  –

for k = 1,..., K represent loadings on other risk factors. In the full conditional setting in equation (1), factor loadings, conditional means of factors, and factor premiums potentially vary over time. The model in equation (1) is written in terms of factor innovations, so rt+1 − γm,t represents the innovation in the m

–  –  –

where λm,t is the price of risk of the market factor, λv,t is the price of aggregate volatility risk, and the λk,t are the prices of risk of the other factors. Note that only if a factor is traded is the conditional mean of a factor equal to its conditional price of risk.



Pages:   || 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 |   ...   | 8 |


Similar works:

«DRC Working Papers Foreign Direct Investment in Emerging Markets CENTRE FOR NEW AND EMERGING MARKETS LONDON BUSINESS SCHOOL No. 15 FDI Spillovers in Emerging Markets: A Literature Review and New Perspectives By Klaus E. Meyer Copenhagen Business School Draft, March 2003 Do not quote CNEM is a Development Research Centre supported by the UK Department for International Development 1 Contents Introduction: Spillovers in a Changing Global Economy 1. 2. Macroeconomic perspectives 3. Knowledge...»

«ROUTLEDGE LIBRARY EDITIONS: SOCIAL THEORY Volume 72 SOCIOLOGICAL THEORY IN USE This page intentionally left blank SOCIOLOGICAL THEORY IN USE KEN MENZIES First published in 1982 This edition first published in 2015 by Routledge 2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon, OX14 4RN and by Routledge 711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017 Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business © 1982 Ken Menzies All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or...»

«Is Relocation to Regional Cities the Equivalent of Abandoning Old people in the Mountains to Die? Is the Long-Term Care Insurance System Sustainable? ―There are two issues to solve. KATO Hisakazu, Professor, School of Political Science and Economics, Meiji University Significance of Long-term Care Insurance and the Year 2025 Problem Launched in April 2000, the Long-Term Care Insurance System is the newest social insurance system in Japan. The hardship faced by people giving family care began...»

«Land, Housing and Property Rights in zimbabwe REPORT MISSION COHRE Africa Programme LAND, HOUSING AND PROPERTY RIGHTS IN zimbabwe CO H R E A f r i ca P r o g r a m m e M i s s i o n R e p o r t, S e p t e m b e r 2 0 0 1 © Copyright 2001, Centre on Housing Rights and Evictions (COHRE) Land, Housing and Property Rights in Zimbabwe Centre on Housing Rights and Evictions, Geneva, Switzerland All rights reserved The Centre on Housing Rights and Evictions is registered in the Netherlands as a...»

«American Economic Review 101 (August 2011): 2157–2181 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.101.5.2157 Panic on the Streets of London: Police, Crime, and the July 2005 Terror Attacks† By Mirko Draca, Stephen Machin, and Robert Witt* Terrorism is arguably the single most significant topic of political discussion of the past decade. In response, a small economics literature has begun to investigate the causes and impacts of terrorism (see Alan B. Krueger 2007 for a summary, or...»

«Dynamic Correlation and Its Determinants: Challenge or a New Tool for Hedging HousePrice Risk? Nathan Berg School of Social Sciences University of Texas at Dallas, Box 830688, GR 31 Richardson, TX 75083 (972) 883-2088 nberg@utdallas.edu Anthony Yanxiang Gu Jones School of Business State University of New York 115D South Hall, 1 College Circle Geneseo, NY 14454 Telephone: (716) 245-5368 Fax: (716) 245-5467 Email: agu@geneseo.edu Donald Lien Department of Economics University of Texas San Antonio...»

«CLOUD COMPUTING IN BUSINESS PROCESSES. A CAR PARTS SUPPLYING COMPANY CASE Kinga Bednarzewska Maria Curie Skłodowska University, Poland kbednarzewska@o2.pl Zbigniew Pastuszak Maria Curie Skłodowska University, Poland z.pastuszak@umcs.pl Abstract: In order to survive in times of crisis and a volatile environment the contemporary organisations have to be quick on their feet i.e. capable of taking decisions swiftly. To this extent, new applications, based on Information Systems and Information...»

«District Centres, Local Centres & Community Facilities Supplementary Planning Guidance October 2010 District Centres, Local Centres and Community Facilities Supplementary Planning Guidance _ October 2010 City and County of Swansea Economic Regeneration and Planning Civic Centre Oystermouth Road Swansea SA1 3SN Tel: 01792 635744 UDP@swansea.gov.uk All plans within this document are orientated to north. Photographs reproduced with the permission of City and County of Swansea and Welsh Assembly...»

«Accounting and Finance An empirical examination of the editorial review processes of accounting journals Ralph Adlera, Gregory Liyanarachchib a Department of Accountancy and Business Law, University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand b Department of Accounting, Economics and Finance, Lincoln University, Christchurch, New Zealand Abstract This study examines the editorial review processes of a broad set of widely circulated and read English-language academic accounting journals. It reports findings...»

«EXPLORING THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF EVERYDAY LIFE ON THE COSTA RICAN FRONTIER FROM AGRARIAN REFORM TO THE PINEAPPLE BOOM A Dissertation Presented in Partial Fulfillment on the Requirements for the Degree of Doctorate of Philosophy with a Major in Environmental Science in the College of Graduate Studies University of Idaho and CATIE by Irene Shaver December 2014 CoMajor Professors: Leontina Hormel, Ph.D. and Nicole Sibelet, Ph.D. ii iii Abstract The focus of this dissertation is to understand the...»

«Guide Green Commerce Commitment to minimise the environmental impact of retailers Guide «Green Commerce» Commitment to minimise the environmental impact of retailers © Generalitat Published by: Generalitat Conselleria de Economía, Industria y Comercio C/ Colón, 32 – 46004 Valencia Design & Layout by: Under-secretariat ISBN: 978-84-482-5771-1 Statutory Deposit (D. L.): V-2219-2012 Printed by: Printed on paper bleached entirely without chlorine and 100% recycled. Contents I. «Green...»

«The Terrorism and Drug Connection in Latin America’s Andean Region Mark S. Steinitz has increasingly helped to finance M ONEY FROM THE ILLICIT DRUG TRADE terrorist groups worldwide, but perhaps nowhere has this development been more significant than in Latin America’s Andes.1 In recent years, funding derived from the cocaine and heroin industry has largely underwritten the terrorism of that troubled region. The principal Andean leftist groups with drug connections are the Armed...»





 
<<  HOME   |    CONTACTS
2016 www.dissertation.xlibx.info - Dissertations, online materials

Materials of this site are available for review, all rights belong to their respective owners.
If you do not agree with the fact that your material is placed on this site, please, email us, we will within 1-2 business days delete him.